Welfare targeting in networks

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmateco.2021.102508Get rights and content

Abstract

This paper investigates welfare targeting for public goods in networks. First, we show that a tax/subsidy scheme (not necessarily budget-balanced) affects each consumer only insofar as it affects his neighbourhood. Second, we show that either a Pareto-improving income redistribution can be found or there exist Negishi weights, which we relate to the network structure. Third, in the case of Cobb–Douglas preferences, we show that a Law of Welfare Targeting holds and links two well-known notions of the comparative statics of policy interventions: neutrality and welfare paradoxical effects. Collectively, our findings uncover the importance of the 1 eigenvalue to economic and social policy: it is an indication of how consumers absorb the impact of income redistribution.

Introduction

Many major challenges facing modern societies (essential infrastructure, information acquisition, emerging infectious disease) relate to enhancing public good provision across different consumers. While market outcomes often provide scope for policy intervention, central planners seldom have the luxury to completely change the state of the economy and implement optimal outcomes. Instead, social planners typically aim to design welfare-improving reforms — involving small changes as in the policy reform literature in the tradition of Dixit (1975) and Guesnerie (1977), and with important policy implications as in Ahmad and Stern (1984).

This paper explores welfare targeting with small tax/subsidy schemes, not necessarily budget-balanced, which are traditionally viewed as a benchmark for broader policy interventions, for the private provision of public goods in networks. In a key contribution, Bramoullé and Kranton (2007) showed that the network context, where local influences are heterogeneous among consumers, is a natural setting to examine the private provision of public goods. Bramoullé et al. (2014) investigated the whole range of strategic substitution and identified a threshold of impact related to the lowest eigenvalue of the network. Below the threshold, the uniqueness and stability of a Nash equilibrium hold. Beyond it, multiple Nash equilibria will in general exist, and stability holds only for corner equilibria. Allouch (2015) extended this model to the non-linear case, with a condition on the normality of the public good which follows the classical (Bergstrom et al., 1986) (henceforth BBV) approach, and showed that their neutrality no longer holds for income redistribution in general networks. Galeotti et al. (2020) analyse optimal policy interventions informed by the eigenvalues of the underlying network of spillovers. Other recent and relevant contributions to the network literature include those by: Galeotti et al., 2010, Ghiglino and Goyal, 2010, Acemoglu et al., 2016, Bourlès et al., 2017, Kinateder and Merlino, 2017, López-Pintado, 2017, Chen et al., 2018, Belhaj and Deroïan, 2019, Elliott and Golub, 2019, Allouch, 2017, Allouch and King, 2019, Akbarpour et al., 2020, Ushchev and Zenou, 2020, Li et al., 2021, Sun et al., 2021, Faias et al., 2015, and Herskovic and Ramos (2020).

First, we establish a property that is key to understanding the impact of welfare targeting in networks. More specifically, we show that a tax/subsidy scheme affects each consumer only insofar as it affects the consumer’s neighbourhood, formed by himself and his neighbours. That is, it is the neighbourhood scheme, rather than the tax/subsidy scheme that affects consumption. Hence the policy implications can be derived by focusing just on the neighbourhood schemes. In particular, neutral tax/subsidy schemes (budget-balanced or not) in general networks are those with null neighbourhood schemes, or equivalently those that are the eigenvectors to the 1 eigenvalue.

Secondly, to inform/guide welfare targeting, we use an approach based on a weighted utilitarian social welfare function. More specifically, the social planner maximises a weighted sum of consumers’ utility functions. We find two mutually exclusive cases — either there is a Pareto-improving income redistribution or, if not, there exist Negishi welfare weights. These Negishi weights provide the implicit welfare weights at the initial equilibrium. In particular, we find that a Pareto-improving income redistribution always exists in the class of networks that has a neutral and budget-unbalanced tax/subsidy scheme, since Negishi weights cannot exist. This finding is very much in the spirit of the BBV neutrality result as it holds for any profile of preferences of consumers. Additionally, in the case of Cobb–Douglas preferences, we show that the feasibility of Pareto-improving reform turns out to be readily interpreted and easily checked from the network structure. As a consequence, our analysis leads to a useful characterisation of welfare targeting.

Thirdly, we provide a link between key, but seemingly unrelated, notions of comparative statics: neutrality and paradoxical welfare effects. In fact, by focusing on tax/subsidy schemes that are also eigenvectors, our analysis shows that in the case of Cobb–Douglas preferences, neutrality (or, equivalently, the 1 eigenvalue) corresponds to the point of policy switch between tax/subsidy schemes where the utility levels of the donors and the recipients move in the same direction as the scheme (normal welfare impact) and tax/subsidy schemes where the utility levels of the donors and the recipients move in the opposite direction (paradoxical welfare impact). In addition, we show that a Law of Welfare Targeting holds for more general tax/subsidy schemes determined by the 1 eigenvalue.

In different settings, our results highlight the importance of the 1 eigenvalue to social and economic outcomes, since our findings identify it as a condition for neutral tax/subsidy schemes, Pareto improvement, and the policy switch. In interpretation, the 1 eigenvalue is an indication of how consumers, via their neighbourhood, absorb the impact of tax/subsidy schemes, and hence of the welfare implications. Despite the frequency with which the 1 eigenvalue appears for many (but not all) networks, as far as we know the 1 eigenvalue is not used as a common measure of network analysis in any other fields, including sociology, computer science, and physics. Given that the 1 eigenvalue provides a key to social and economic outcomes, perhaps its relationship to the underlying network structure could usefully be studied alongside classic network statistics such as the highest, the second, and lately the lowest eigenvalues.

The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 sets out the model and Section 3 investigates welfare targeting. Section 4 looks at Pareto improvement and Negishi weights and Section 5 provides a new perspective on neutrality and paradoxical welfare effects. Section 6 concludes the paper. An Appendix provides proofs of the propositions and corollaries.

Section snippets

The model

We consider a society comprising n consumers in N={1,,n} who occupy the nodes of a fixed network g of social interactions. Let G=[gij] denote the adjacency matrix of the network g, where gij=1 indicates that consumer ij are neighbours and gij=0 otherwise. The adjacency matrix of the network, G, is symmetric with non-negative entries and therefore has a complete set of real eigenvalues (not necessarily distinct), denoted by λmax(G)=λ1λ2λn=λmin(G), where λmax(G) is the largest eigenvalue

Welfare targeting

In this paper, we investigate welfare targeting by a social planner in networks. The idea is that implementing a welfare-efficient outcome is typically unachievable because it requires a significant change from the existing state of the economy. More realistic are small tax/subsidy schemes, which induce infinitesimal changes that are welfare-improving and equilibrium-preserving as in Dixit, 1975, Guesnerie, 1977, and Ahmad and Stern (1984).

Let q=(q1,,qn) be the Nash equilibrium associated

Pareto improvement vs. Negishi weights

To inform welfare targeting, we follow an approach based on a weighted utilitarian social welfare function with welfare weights given by rR++n. Hence the social welfare effect of a tax/subsidy scheme s is rΔv(s).

An interesting set of welfare weights are Negishi weights (named after Negishi (1960)), which neutralise any impact of policy change from income redistribution at the initial equilibrium, and are hence defined by rΔv(s)=0 for any budget-balanced tax/subsidy scheme s. Negishi weights

Policy switch and the 1 eigenvalue

Next we show how welfare targeting in networks, which accounts for heterogeneity of local interactions, provides a link between the neutrality and general welfare effects. Indeed, observe that when a Pareto-improving income redistribution exists, it holds that the donors’ utility level must move in the opposite direction to the tax/subsidy scheme. In fact, this is an example of a weak transfer paradox. On the contrary, a strong transfer paradox corresponds to the case where the utility levels

Conclusion

In this paper, we have shown that welfare targeting, which accounts for heterogeneity of local interactions, enables us to derive new results and policy insights. We have also identified the 1 eigenvalue of the network as the condition for neutral tax/subsidy schemes, a sufficient condition for Pareto improvement and a policy switch point between consumers acting on or counteracting policy intervention.

The 1 eigenvalue is not a common measure of network analysis in any other fields, including

Declaration of Competing Interest

The authors declare that they have no known competing financial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper.

References (40)

  • DixitAvinash

    Welfare effects of tax and price changes

    J. Public Econ.

    (1975)
  • FaiasMarta et al.

    On neutrality with multiple private and public goods

    Math. Soc. Sci.

    (2015)
  • GuesnerieRoger

    On the direction of tax reform

    J. Public Econ.

    (1977)
  • UshchevPhilip et al.

    Social norms in networks

    J. Econom. Theory

    (2020)
  • YangZili et al.

    Magnitude and direction of technological transfers for mitigating GHG emissions

    Energy Econ.

    (2006)
  • AbbottJoshua K. et al.

    Following the golden rule: Negishi welfare weights without apology

    (2014)
  • AkbarpourMohammad et al.

    Just a Few Seeds More: Value of Network Information for DiffusionSSRN Scholarly Paper ID 3062830

    (2020)
  • AllouchNizar et al.

    Constrained public goods in networks

    J. Public Econ. Theory

    (2019)
  • BeckerGary S.

    A Theory of Social InteractionsWorking Paper 42

    (1974)
  • BıyıkogluTürker et al.

    Some notes on spectra of cographs

    Ars Combin.

    (2011)
  • Cited by (2)

    • Farsighted manipulation and exploitation in networks

      2021, Journal of Economic Theory
      Citation Excerpt :

      It also demonstrates that the lowest eigenvalue of the adjacency matrix of the network is key to equilibrium analysis. Allouch (2015) and Allouch and King (2021) study the effects of wealth redistribution on the provision of the local public good and on the players' welfare. Galeotti and Goyal (2010) and Choi et al. (2019) extend the model and allow players not only to invest in public good provision, but also in building up their connections.

    We would like to thank James Andreoni, Ted Bergstrom, Sebastian Bervoets, Larry Blume, Yann Bramoullé, Sergio Currarini, Matthew Elliott, Andrea Galeotti, Ben Golub, Sanjeev Goyal, Roger Guesnerie, Jaromír Kovár̂ík, Miltos Makris, Hervé Moulin, and Junjie Zhou for valuable discussions, and one anonymous reviewer for their helpful comments and suggestions. For support, Nizar Allouch thanks ANR 18-CE26-0020-01.

    View full text